יהדות בריטניה: הדג מסריח מהראש

לא תגורו מפני איש

הרב אליהו קאופמן

      מה שאירע בלונדון – בירת בריטניה, בפרשת העריות של הדיין יונתן אברהם, הוא המשך למה שהתחיל שם לפני מספר שנים עם הרב חיים הלפרין. שניהם – דרך אגב, תושבי השכונה החרדית המודרנית “גלדרס גרין”. כאשר התפוצצה פרשת הרב חיים הלפרין מיד החלו הניסיונות לטייח ולעקם את האמת. במוצאי שבת שלאחר שמחת תורה של אותה שנה הוזמן הרב חיים הלפרין לביתו של הדיין חנוך הרנטרויא, משכונת “הנדון” הסמוכה ל”גלדרס גרין”. הרב הלפרין – רב בית המדרש שברח’ “בריג’ ליין 65 ב”גלדרס גרין”, היה בטוח שהוא מוזמן לישיבת רבנים של האזור הצפון – מערבי של לונדון. זה לא היה מופרך כי ישיבות כאלה התקיימו מידי פעם ואליה הגיעו רבני “גלדרס גרין” ו”הנדון” לטכס עצה ביחס לעמדה ולפעילות כזו או אחרת בלונדון. בבית הרב ערנטרויא – זקן הדיינים והרבנים באזור ובעבר אב”ד בית הדין של ה”יוניטד סינגוג” בלונדון ובבריטניה (“בית הדין של המדינה”), אמנם הגיעו כול רבני האזור אבל זו הייתה מלכודת ה”כיפה אדומה” עבור הרב חיים הלפרין. היו שם הרבנים ווינגרטן, הגר, רוברטס והיו שם גם הדיינים ליכטנשטיין, גאלי ואברהם ועוד רבנים ודיינים אחרים. אבל הנושא לא היה עניין של פעילות תורתית או משהו דומה אלא היציאה לאור השמש של מעלליו של הרב חיים הלפרין בעשרות נשים חרדיות, כולל נשואות. לא ארחיב כאן על מעלליו של ה”רב החסידי” והשמנמן מפאת הצניעות אבל רק אציין שבאחד המקרים הוא טען כלפי נערה חרדית שקצת ירדה מהדרך כי “אם אני לא אעשה לך את זה אז גויים טמאים יעשו לך את זה ויטמאו אותך”. כך לפחות הופץ הסיפור שאולי הינו אמת ואולי הוא אגדה. הרב הלפרין עמד מול כול אותם הרבנים ופרץ בבכי. הוא הודה במעשיו והבטיח לעזוב את לונדון בזמן קצר ביותר. אבל בבוקרו של יום שני שאח”כ הגלגל התהפך.

         באותם ימים עוד היה בחיים נשיא ארגון “כדתיא” – ארגון הגג של הקהילות החרדיות בבריטניה, הרב אלחנן הלפרין מ”גלדרס גרין, אביו של הרב חיים הלפרין. על מה שהסכים הרב הלפרין – לעזוב את לונדון, לא הסכים האב ועימו שני בניו משה ודוד, אחייו של חיים. משפחת הלפרין – ובראשם האב הזקן, יצאה חוצץ נגד סילוקו של הרב חיים הלפרין מלונדון והאב אף ענה כי “הכול עלילה”. הם ניסו לתלות זאת במלחמת ה”ליטאים נגד הרב החסידי חיים הלפרין”. לימים הובהר כי בוודאי שלא כך היו הדברים משום שבין רבני “גלדרס גרין”, שקמו נגד חיים הלפרין, היה גם הרב הגר, רב בית כנסת מרכזי וכולל גדול ב”גלדרס גרין”. אבל הרב אלחנן הלפרין לא הרפה וכנגד העובדות נגד בנו חיים הוא גייס “שושלת יוחסין” שבה טען כי בנו הוא צאצא של ה”דברי חיים” מצאנז וכול הפוגע בבנו הרי שה”דברי חיים” ינקום בו משמים. בוודאי שכול הסיפור הזה מופרך שהרי יצחק אבינו מעולם לא נקם משמים במי שנלחם בעשיו בנו. לחצה של משפחת הלפרין – לטיהורו של חיים, הפך לאובססיבי ולאף לאלים. כך למשל נעל הרב משה הלפרין (כיום הוא יורשו של אביו בבית המדרש המרכזי – “בית שמואל”, ב”גלדרזס גרין”) את אב”ד “כדתיא” – הרב אפרים פדובא מ”סטמפורד היל”, בבית אביו ואיים לא לתת לו לצאת מהבית עד שהרב פדובא ישנה ויחתום שחזר בו כנגד אחיו חיים. כך ניסו האח דוד הלפרין ועסקן מרכזי מ”גלדרס גרין” להלך אימים על הנשים הנפגעות ועל בעליהן של הנשואות ולאיים עליהם לבטל את תלונותיהם במשטרת לונדון. התוצאות היו שהרב חיים הלפרין אמנם נותר ב”גלדרס גרין” אך הוא יצא מכך ב”שן ועין”.

       בית מדרשו של הרב חיים הלפרין התרוקן מעשרות מתפללים חשובים ואמידים שהחליטו שזה לא יהיה יותר רבם. במקומו של הלפרין הם בחרו את הרב יוסף וויינברג – לשעבר ראש ישיבת וינה, ונכדו הגדול של הרב המנוח ומיסד החינוך החרדי בבריטניה, הרב שמלק’ה פינטר זצ”ל. משפחת הלפרין ניסתה להפעיל כוחניות נגד שליחתו של הרב ווינברג ללונדון אך נכשלה. גם במישור המשפחתי נאלץ הרב הלפרין להתקפל. הרב חיים הלפרין היה המועמד הטבעי לרשת אביו – כרב בית המדרש המרכזי ב”גלדרס גרין” (“בית שמואל”) אך הפרשה גרמה לכך שהיורש הפך להיות אחיו, הרב משה הלפרין, המכהן כיום כרב בית המדרש במקומו של אביו המנוח, הרב אלחנן הלפרין. גם מעמדו של הרב חיים הלפרין – כדיין ב”כדתיא” החרדית, עורער ונשר. אבל מנגד הוא עזב את העיר, הוא ממשיך לתפקד כרב של בית מדרש פרטי והתלונות נגדו במשטרה נסגרו ע”י אילוץ הנשים לחזור בהן. היה נכון שאילו תמורת סגירת התלונות הללו הוא יפסיק לתפקד כרב בלונדון ויעזוב את העיר אבל כאמור, זה לא קרה. יש לציין כי יותר מעשור לפני התפוצצות פרשת הרב חיים הלפרין הרי שכותב שורות אלה שמע על דברים דומים על הרב הלפרין מדיין מרכזי בלונדון, ואף לו מאותו דיין כי הרב חיים הלפרין קיצר ימי נידה לנשות חלק מבאי בית הכנסת שלו, שלא עפ”י ההלכה. תלמיד חכם ב”סטמפורד היל” טען בפרשה שהוא אמנם איננו יודע פרטים ממשיים על מעללי ההלפרין הזה אבל לאחר שראה ושמע מיהן מספר נשים שהלכו ל”התייעצויות” אצל הרב חיים הלפרין הרי שהוא לא מתפלא על פיצוץ הפרשה הזו. אבל הנזק הגדול נעשה בכך שבראות אחרים ש”לית דין ולית דיין” כנגד העריות הללו הלך המצב והדרדר לכך שגם אחרים – כולל רבנים ודיינים, זלזלו בענייני הצניעות והעריות.  ב”סטמפורד היל” ניסו לא מעטים לגונן על חיים הלפרין משום היותו חסידי, אחרים טענו כי עשה זאת כ”מסג’ רפואי” וברשותן של הנשים, והיו בכלל שניסו לטעון כי “עדות נשים היא פסולה”. אין ספק שהמגינים הללו הזיקו לנושא עצמו ודרדרו את במצב תוך זלזול בצניעות והורדתה עוד יותר למטה ממה שהיתה עד אז. וכך הגענו לפרשת יונתן אברהם – דיין ב”בית הדין של לונדון והמדינה”.

       הסיפור החדש התפוצץ בשבועות האחרונים. הדיין הלה – אף הוא תושב “גלדרס גרין”, נתפס ע”י בלש פרטי כשהוא מטמא בזנות אשת איש, שהיא ובעלה הגיעו אליו לצורך “שלום בית”. לעומת הרב חיים הלפרין – הרי שהדיין הזה התפטר מיד מכול תפקידיו. כנראה שחסר לו ה”ייחוס” המזרח אירופאי והחסידי שהיה לחיים הלפרין. אבל גם עליו מנסים חבריו לגונן. כך למשל עשה הדיין הוותיק חנוך ערנטרויא, שבעבר היה אב”ד בית הדין שבו כיהן הדיין אברהם שסרח, וכיום ערנטרויא עומד בראש בית הדין האירופאי של “ועידת רבני אירופה” ועוסק בגיורים די בעיתיים, כאשר חלק מה”גרים” הללו נדחפים על ידו להפוך ל”רבנים” שאפילו מעורבים כ”דיינים”, שלא עפ”י “שולחן ערוך”. דיין ערנטרויא – שבפרשת חיים הלפרין הוא היה נחרץ ביותר ולא ניסה למצוא “קולות” להשתקת הרעש סביב הפרשה, הרי שבפרשת דיין אברהם הוא תלה בבתי הכנסת ב”גלדרס גרין” מודעה המבקשת לאסור בבתי כנסת ובשולחנות שבת את הדיבור על הפרשה הזו. היחיד ששבר את בקשתו היה הרב אהרון בצוץ, רב קהילת הספרדים ועדות המזרח, ששמה “כנסת יחזקאל”.

        הרב אהרון בסוס בנה את קהילתו בעשר אצבעות. בשנת 1990 הוא היה רב צעיר ב”גלדרס גרין” שאנשיו חיפשו לו פעם עשירי למניין ברחובה של עיר. אבל עם השנים הוא הפך את קהילתו לקהילה הספרדית המרכזית והגדולה של בריטניה. כיום – כמעט שלושים שנה אח”כ, יש לו סניף אפילו בשכונת רמת בית שמש א’ שבבית שמש, והקהילה שלו שם נקראת “מעם לועז”. אלה הם בני הדור השני והשלישי שגידל הרב בצוץ לתורה ולמצוות בבריטניה ולימים עלו לישראל ובנו את קהילתם בבית שמש. אבל בשנים האחרונות פרסומו יצא בשל עמידתו בפסוק “לא תגורו מפני איש”. עוד לפני פרשת דיין אברהם שסרח הוא התעמת עם אחד בשם דואק, שהגיע מארה”ב והפך לעמוד ה”דיינות” בבית הדין של ה”ספרדים – פורטוגזים” בלונדון. בית דין זה הוא הרביעי בגודלו בין בתי הדין היהודיים בבריטניה וגם הפחות חשוב שבהם. רוב היהדות הדתית של יוצאי המזרח חברים בבתי הדין של ה”יונייטד סינגגוג” (“בית הדין של המדינה”), בית הדין של “חברת בני ישראל” (“פדריישן”) והחרדים חברים ב”כדתיה”. הדיינות והכשרות של בית הדין הקטן הזה מזערית אבל בית הדין הזה עשיר מאוד מהימים שלפני התבוללותם של צאצאי היהודים הספרדים והפורטוגזים. דואק הגיע ללונדון מארה”ב לאחר שבני עדתו (עדת יוצאי העיר חלב שבסוריה) הראו לו את הדרך לטיסה חד כיוונית לבריטניה בשל עמדותיו הפרו רפורמיות והפרו קונסרבטיוויות, ובעיקר בשל תמיכתו בהכרה לאנשי התועבה. האיש הזה הוא חתנה של הבת הסוררת והמורדת של הגר”ע יוסף – גב’ זכייה בר שלום, שגם אחייה הכריזו מלחמה עליה ועל חתנה המפוקפק. מרגע בואו ללונדון החל דואק בסערות פרובוקטיביות, ובראשן הצהרותיו בדבר תמיכתו בהכרה בתועבות ובמתן לגיטימציה לאנשי התועבות. באחרונה העלה רעיונות דומים גם “רבה הראשי” של בריטניה – אפרים מירוויס, ששלח חוזר חוצפני לתלמודי התורה החרדים לאמץ את ההכרה בתועבות ובאנשיהם. כאשר אותו דואק החל בהצהרותיו הפרובוקטיביות הרי שהרב בצוץ יצא מיד נגדו. הרב בצוץ – השייך ל”כדתיא”, האמין שבית הדין של החרדים יעמוד מאחוריו אך מה הופתע הלה כאשר הללו רק גמגמו וטענו כי “זהו עניין פנימי של הספרדים”. מסתבר שאם דיין דונר וחבריו מ”כדתיא” היו חיים בימי שבתאי צבי ימ”ש הם היו עונים ל”חכם צבי” את אותה תשובה (…). זו לא הייתה הפעם הראשונה שב”כדתיא” פסחו על שני הסעיפים. לפני יותר מעשור הם פחדו לצאת נגד “גר צדק” מפוקפק שניסה להשתלט, בעזרת כספו, על בתי הדינים בלונדון ולהכניס שם “גרים” כלבבו ע”י הטיית דיני היהדות, ולימים גם הוא הואשם בענייני אי קיום הלכות “אבן העזר”. בית הכנסת של אותו האיש – בשכונת “הנדון”, הסתנף אז ל…”כדתיא”, גם כשבאירועי קידושים ושמחות לא הייתה שם מחיצה בין אנשים לנשים! כאשר עלה עניינו של דואק לכותרות הדיונים בבריטניה הרי שמלבד הרב בצוץ מסתבר שכול הדיינים והרבנים מלאו פיהם מים ורק בחדרי חדרים דיברו על הסכנה באיש הזה, שלמעשה הינו רפורמי. דייני בית הדין של דואק, הספרדים – פורטוגזים, כמובן ששתקו מתוך לויאליות ל”קולגה”. גם בית הדין של חברת “בני ישראל” שתק וכך גם “בית הדין של המדינה”. באותם ימים הוביל את סתימת הפיות לטובת דואק – מטעם “בית הדין של המדינה”, אותו דיין נואף ששמו יונתן אברהם, זה שנתפס לימים באשת איש. אברהם לא התבייש לצלצל שוב ושוב לרב בצוץ ולבקש ממנו להרפות מדואק הרפורמי, ולאחר שהרב בצוץ סירב הרי שאברהם התעלם ממנו במפגשי רבנים וסובב ממנו את ראשו כדי לא לברכו באמירת שלום. לא במקרה חז”ל טענו כי התמיכה בעבודה זרה (במקרה שלנו אלה הרפורמים …) מביאה לגילוי עריות. לא במקרה מי שתומך בחיי “דו קיום” עם אנשי התועבות הוא בעצמו עובר על אשת איש, ומי יודע איזה עוד עבירות הוא ביצע. ממצאי הבלש הפרטי מסתבר שהדיין הנאלח הזה נפגש עם אשת האיש לא רק במלונות אלא גם במקומות מפוקפקים שהצניעות והכשרות מהם והלאה. קולו של דיין ערנטרויא – “דיין העל” של בריטניה, לא נשמע בכול פרשת אותו הדואק וכך גם כאשר הרב מירוויס שלח את חוזר התועבה לבתי הספר החרדים. כאן יש לציין כי כבר בימיה של גב’ מרגרט תאצ’ר – ראש ממשלת בריטניה הגדולה של שנות השמונים של המאה העשרים, כבר עלה עניין קבלת אנשי התועבה כחלק משינויים דתיים בבריטניה, אך בעוד שהכמורה האנגליקנית הייתה מוכנה להתפשר בעניין הרי ש”הרב הראשי” של בריטניה דאז, הלורד עמנואל יעקובובי’ץ, סירב לכך בכול מאודו ולבסוף הכמורה האנגליקנית שינתה את דעתה. על כך יצאה גב’ תאצ’ר השמרנית לטובתו של הלורד יעקובובי’ץ והאדירה את שמו בעוד שכלפי הכמרים היא פלטה מילות זלזול.

       את דיין אברהם לא מספיק להדיח מתפקידיו הרבניים אלא שיש גם לשלול ממנו את זכותו להעביר שיעורי תורה בכול אתר ואתר, ואף יש לדאוג שיעזוב את לונדון. אבל כדי לעשות זאת צריכים רבני בריטניה לשנות את דרכם ואפיים ולהתחיל להיאבק נגד כול מי שפורץ גדר באשר היא. המאבק נגד הרפורמי דואק ונגד הנואפים הלפרין ואברהם חייבת להיות ברורה, חדה וללא משוא פנים. את המאמר הזה הבאתי משום שמישהו צריך לכתוב ולא לשתוק על ירידת קרנה של התורה והיהדות בבריטניה, ועוד כשהדג הרבני מסריח מראשו.

מאתר יורה דעה, כאן.

Deciphering the Research on Vaccines to Make Health Care Decisions

New York Times Editorial On Vaccines: A Pseudoscience Mess!

(Note: My wife vetoed my initial headline: Failing New York Times Op-Ed Full of Fake Vaccine News.  She claims that my sense of humor does not translate to all.)

The lead New York Times (NYT) editorial today is titled, “Know The Enemy.” According to the NYT, the “enemy” is anyone who questions the safety and efficacy of any vaccine.

I guess that makes me the enemy. I thought I was a board-certified physician trying to read and decipher the research on vaccines to help guide my patients on how to make their best health care decisions.

The NYT states, “Leading global health threats typically are caused by the plagues and perils of low-income countries — but vaccine hesitancy is as American as can be.” Both parts of that sentence are correct.

In the early 20th Century, infection was the number one killer of Americans and it killed a high percentage of our youth. However, by the 1950’s infection rates for nearly every childhood vaccine- preventable illness (as well as other infectious illnesses like scarlet fever) had drastically declined—BEFORE vaccines were developed and mandated. In fact, for the major vaccine-preventable illnesses such as measles, mumps, diphtheria, and pertussis, the death rate declined well over 90% BEFORE vaccines were mandated. How did that occur? The death rate from infectious diseases declined not by vaccination, but by public health measures. This includes providing clean water to our houses and safely removing waste products.

Did vaccines lower the death rate for their respective illnesses? We don’t know since the rates were already declining dramatically before the mass vaccination program began. To imply that vaccines were responsible for this dramatic decline in pediatric infectious deaths in the 20th Century is nothing more than FAKE NEWS!

One of the best indicators of the health of a country is the infant mortality rate. Researchers correlated the number of vaccines given to infants and the mortality rate for ages five and under. Guess who gave the most vaccines and guess who had the highest infant mortality rate? If you guessed the US, you win.

The NYT states, “On the internet, anti-vaccine propaganda has outpaced pro-vaccine public health information. The anti-vaxxers, as they are colloquially known, have hundreds of websites promoting their message, a roster of tech- and media-savvy influencers and an aggressive political arm that includes at least a dozen political action committees.”

Well, in this case, there is just me. And, I am not that tech-savvy.

I don’t write anti-vaccine propaganda. I write about the science behind vaccines. And, if you study the science behind vaccines, it is hard not to question the wisdom of injecting our young with too many toxic-laden vaccines.

“The C.D.C., the nation’s leading public health agency, has a website with accurate information, but no loud public voice,” writes the NYT. The CDC is a cesspool of corruption, according to Robert F. Kennedy Jr. In fact, the CDC has a senior scientist who has assumed whistle-blower status claiming that published studies (by the CDC) looking at whether the MMR vaccine causes autism were fraudulent. The whistle-blower has stated, under oath, that senior CDC managers directed the whistle-blower and others to destroy and alter the data in order to hide the truth. The data, released by the whistle-blower, did show a strong correlation with the MMR vaccine and autism.

Why doesn’t the NYT write a lead op-ed demanding that the CDC whistle-blower testify in front of Congress about his allegations? To date, it has been over four years since the whistle-blower came forward. To date, he has not testified in front of Congress and the CDC has blocked his testimony in other settings. To date, the NYT has failed to write ONE article about this situation. Perhaps the CDC has no loud voice because it is too busy covering up the truth about vaccines. If there is nothing to hide, then why doesn’t the whistle-blower testify? Why has the CDC gagged him from speaking?

Further in the op-ed, the NYT writes, “The consequences of this disparity are substantial: a surge in outbreaks of measles, mumps, pertussis and other diseases; an increase in influenza deaths; and dismal rates of HPV vaccination, which doctors say could effectively wipe out cervical cancer if it were better utilized.”

Would declining vaccine rates increase the susceptibility for some of the vaccinated illnesses? Yes. For example, measles and chickenpox illnesses will increase if we stop vaccinating for these illnesses. But, children rarely die from measles and chickenpox in modern countries. These illnesses are often treated with supportive care and for the vast majority recovery from the illness is uneventful.

Cervical cancer deaths have rapidly fallen not from vaccines, but better medical care such as the Pap smear.  The HPV vaccine has never been shown to prevent cancer and probably will not in the future.  And, there are too many side effects from the HPV vaccine to recommend its use for a relatively uncommon cancer. Can measles and chickenpox cause serious effects including death? Yes. So can the vaccines.

The NYT mentions the pro-vaccine researchers are having “…to counter pseudoscience with fact” in order to prove vaccines are safe and effective.

Pseudoscience? There is no greater example of pseudoscience than saying it is safe to inject toxic items like mercury, aluminum and formaldehyde into any living being, much less a newborn infant.

Pseudoscience? How about the pseudoscience by not comparing a new vaccine with a placebo to show that it is safe. However, in today’s world, in regards to vaccines, pseudoscience rules.  The fact is that childhood vaccines have not been studied against a true placebo (except for one small HPV study which found much higher adverse effects in the HPV group compared to the placebo). Big Pharma studies the vaccines against other vaccines and other toxic agents which hide the true adverse effects of vaccines.

Pseudoscience? Where are the CDC studies comparing vaccinated versus unvaccinated? This simple study could put to rest the idea that vaccines cause too many problems. The CDC refuses to do a vaccinated versus unvaccinated study even though Congress has asked for this.

The NYT mentioned the California Disneyland measles outbreak twice. Here are the facts about the Disneyland measles outbreak. A total of 147 people were sickened with measles. No deaths were reported. Of those sickened with measles, 45% were unvaccinated. Of the remaining subjects, 18% were vaccinated and 38% had unknown vaccination status. Perhaps the NYT editorial board should re-watch the Brady Bunch episode where the Brady children become infected with measles. Marcia Brady stated, “If you have to get sick, sure can’t beat the measles.”

Continue reading…

From Dr. Brownstein, here.

The State’s ‘Libertarian’ Efficiency Expert, Milton Friedman: Governmental Efficiency Is a Threat to Freedom

Is a Free Society Stable? MILTON FRIEDMAN*

THERE IS A STRONG TENDENCY for all of us to regard what is as if it were the “natural” or “normal” state of affairs, to lack perspective because of the tyranny of the status quo. It is, therefore, well, from time to time, to make a deliberate effort to look at things in a broader context. In such a context anything approaching a free society is an exceedingly rare event. Only during short intervals in man’s recorded history has there been anything approaching what we would call a free society in existence over any appreciable part of the globe. And even during such intervals, as at the moment, the greater part of mankind has lived under regimes that could by no stretch of the imagination be called free.

This casual empirical observation raises the question whether a free society may not be a system in unstable equilibrium. If one were to take a purely historical point of view, one would have to say that the “normal,” in the sense of average, state of mankind is a state of tyranny and despotism. Perhaps this is the equilibrium state of society that tends to arise in the relation of man to his fellows. Perhaps highly special circumstances must exist to render a free society possible. And perhaps these special circumstances, the existence of which account for the rare episodes of freedom, are themselves by their nature transitory, so that the kind of society we all of us believe in is highly unlikely to be maintained, even if once attained.

This problem has, of course, been extensively discussed in the literature. In his great book, Lectures on Law and Public Opinion in the Nineteenth Century, written at the end of the nineteenth century, A. V. Dicey discusses a very similar question. How was it, he asks, that toward the end of the nineteenth century there seemed to be a shift in English public opinion away from the doctrine of liberalism and toward collectivism, even though just prior to the shift, individualism and laisser-faire were at something like their high tide, seemed to have captured English public opinion, and seemed to be producing the results that their proponents had promised in the form of an expansion of economic activity, a rise in the standard of life, and the like?

As you may recall, Dicey dates the change in public opinion in Britain away from individualism and toward collectivism at about 1870-90. Dicey answers his question by essentially reversing it, saying that in its original form, it may be a foolish question. Perhaps the relevant question is not why people turned away from individualism toward collectivism, but how they were induced to accept the queer notion of individualism in the first place. The argument for a free society, he goes on to say, is a very subtle and sophisticated argument. At every point, it depends on the indirect rather than the direct effect of the policy followed. If one is concerned to remedy clear evils in a society, as everyone is, the natural reaction is to say, “let’s do something about it,” and the “us” in this statement will in a large number of cases be translated into the “government,” so the natural reaction is to pass a law. The argument that maybe the attempt to correct this particular evil by extending the hand of the government will have indirect effects whose aggregate consequences may be far worse than any direct benefits that flow from the action taken is, after all, a rather sophisticated argument. And yet, this is the kind of argument that underlies a belief in a free or laisser-faire society.

If you look at each evil as it arises, in and of itself, there will almost always tend to be strong pressures to do something about it. This will be so because the direct effects are clear and obvious while the indirect effects are remote and devious and because there tends to be a concentrated group of people who have strong interests in favor of a particular measure whereas the opponents, like the indirect effects of the measure, are diffused. One can cite example after example along this line. Indeed, I think it is true that most crude fallacies about economic policies derive from neglecting the indirect effects of the policies followed.

The tariff is one example. The benefits that are alleged to flow from a tariff are clear and obvious. If a tariff is imposed, a specified group of people, whose names can almost be listed, seem to be benefited in the first instance. The harm that is wrought by the tariff is borne by people whose names one does not know and who are unlikely themselves to know that they are or will be harmed. The tariff does most harm to people who have special capacities for producing the exports that would pay for the goods that would be imported in the absence of a tariff. With a tariff in effect, the potential export industry may never exist and no one will ever know that he might have been employed in it or who would have been. The indirect harm to consumers via a more inefficient allocation of resources and higher prices for the resulting products are spread even more thinly through the society. Thus the case for a tariff seems quite clear on first glance. And this is true in case after case.

This natural tendency to engage in state action in specific instances can, it would seem, and this is Dicey’s argument, be offset only by a widespread general acceptance of a philosophy of non-interference, by a general presumption against undertaking any one of a large class of actions. And, says Dicey, what is really amazing and surprising is that for so long a period as a few decades, sufficiently widespread public opinion developed in Britian in favor of the general principle of non-intervention and laisser-faire as to overcome the natural tendency to pass a law for the particular cases. As soon as this general presumption weakened, it meant the emergence of a climate of opinion in favor of specific government intervention.

Dicey’s argument is enormously strengthened by an asymmetry between a shift toward individualism and a shift away from it. In the first place, there is what I have called the tyranny of the status quo. Anyone who wants to see how strong that tyranny is can do no better, I believe, than to read Dicey’s book now. On reading it, he will discover how extreme and extensive a collectivist he is, as judged by the kinds of standards for governmental action that seemed obvious and appropriate to Dicey when he wrote his lectures. In discussing issues of this kind, the tendency always is to take what is for granted, to assume that it is perfectly all right and reasonable, and that the problem to argue about is the next step. This tends to mean that movements in any one direction are difficult to reverse. A second source of asymmetry is the general dilemma that faces the liberal—tolerance of the intolerant. The belief in individualism includes the belief in tolerating the intolerant. It includes the belief that the society is only worth defending if it is one in which we resort to persuasion rather than to force and in which we defend freedom of discussion on the part of those who would undermine the system itself. If one departs from a free society, the people in power in a collectivist society will not hesitate to use force to keep it from being changed. Under such circumstances, it is more difficult to achieve a revolution that would convert a totalitarian or collectivist society into an individualist society than it is to do the reverse. From the point of view of the forces that may work in the direction of rendering a free society an unstable system, this is certainly one of the most important that strengthens Dicey’s general argument.

PERHAPS THE MOST FAMOUS argument alleging the instability of a free enterprise or capitalist society is the Marxian. Marx argued that there were inherent historical tendencies within a capitalist society that would tend to lead to its destruction. As you know, he predicted that as it developed, capitalism would produce a division of society into sharp classes, the impoverishment of the masses, the despoilment of the middle classes, and a declining rate of profit. He predicted that the combined result would be a class struggle in which the class of the “expropriated” or the proletarian class would assume power.

Marx’s analysis is at least in part to be regarded as a scientific analysis attempting to derive hypotheses that could be used to predict consequences that were likely to occur. His predictions have uniformly been wrong; none of the major consequences that he predicted has in fact occurred. Instead of a widening split among classes, there has tended to be a reduction of class barriers. Instead of a despoilment of the middle class, there has tended to be, if anything, an increase in the middle class relative to the extremes. Instead of the impoverishment of the masses, there has been the largest rise in the standard of life of the masses that history has ever seen. We must therefore reject his theory as having been disproved.

The lack of validity of Marx’s theory does not mean that it has been unimportant. It had the enormous importance of leading many, if not a majority, of the intellectual and ruling classes to regard tendencies of the kind he predicted as inevitable, thereby leading them to interpret what did go on in different terms than they otherwise would. Perhaps the most striking example has been the extent to which intellectuals, and people in general, have taken it for granted that the development of a capitalist society has meant an increased concentration of industrial power and an increase in the degree of monopoly. Though this view has largely reflected a confusion between changes in absolute size and changes in relative size, in part also, I think, it was produced by the fact that this was something they were told by Marx to look for. I don’t mean to attribute this view solely to the Marxian influence. But I think that in this and other instances, the Marxian argument has indirectly affected the patterns of thinking of a great many people including many who would regard themselves as strongly anti-Marxian. Indeed, in many ways, the ideas have been most potent when they have lost their labels. In this way, Marx’s ideas had an enormous intellectual importance, even though his scientific analysis and predictions have all been contradicted by experience.

In more recent times, Joseph Schumpeter has offered a more subtle and intellectually more satisfactory defense of essentially the Marxian conclusion. Schumpeter’s attitude toward Marx is rather interesting. He demonstrates that Marx was wrong in every separate particular, yet proceeds both to accept the major import of his conclusions and to argue that Marx was a very great man. Whereas Marx’s view was that capitalism would destroy itself by its failure, Schumpeter’s view was that capitalism would destroy itself by its success. Schumpeter believed that large scale enterprises and monopoly have real advantages in promoting technological progress and growth and that these advantages would give them a competitive edge in the economic struggle. The success of capitalism would therefore, he argued, be associated with a growth of very large enterprises, and with the spread of something like semi-monopoly over the industrial scene. In its turn, he thought that this development would tend to convert businessmen into bureaucrats. Large organizations have much in common whether they are governmental or private. They inevitably, he believed, produced an increasing separation between the ultimate owners of the enterprises and the individuals who were in positions of importance in managing the enterprises. Such individuals are induced to place high values upon technical performance and to become adaptable to a kind of civil-service socialist organization of society. In addition, this process would create the kind of skills in the managerial elite that would be necessary in order to have a collectivist or governmentally controlled society. The development of this bureaucratic elite with its tendency to place greater and greater emphasis on security and stability and to accept centralized control would tend, he believed, to have the effect of establishing a climate of opinion highly favorable to a shift to an explicitly socialized and centralized state.

The view that Schumpeter expressed has much in common with what Burnham labelled a managerial revolution although the two are not by any means the same. There is also much in common between Schumpeter’s analysis and the distinction that Veblen drew in his analysis of the price system between the roles of entrepreneurs and engineers, between “business” and “industry.” There are also large differences. Veblen saw the engineer as the productive force in the society, the entrepreneur as the destructive force. Schumpeter, if anything, saw matters the other way. He saw the entrepreneur as the creative force in society, and the engineer as simply his handmaiden. But I think there is much in common between the two analyses with respect to the belief that power would tend to shift from the one to the other.

For myself, I must confess that while I find Schumpeter’s analysis intriguing and intellectually fascinating, I cannot accept his thesis. It seems to me to reflect in large part a widespread bias that emphasizes the large and few as opposed to the small and numerous, a tendency to see the merits of scale and not to recognize the merits of large numbers of separate people working in diverse activities. In any event, so far as one can judge, there has been no striking tendency in experience toward an increasing concentration of economic activity in large bureaucratic private enterprises. Some enormous enterprises have of course arisen. But there has also been a very rapid growth in small enterprises. What has happened in this country at least is that the large enterprises have tended to be concentrated in communication and manufacturing. These industries have tended to account for a roughly constant proportion of total economic activity. Small enterprises have tended to be concentrated in agriculture and services. Agriculture has declined in importance and in the number of enterprises, while the service industries have grown in both. If one leaves government aside, as Schumpeter’s thesis requires one to do, so far as one can judge from the evidence, there seems to have been no particularly consistent tendency for the fraction of economic activity which is carried on in any given percentage of the enterprises to have grown. What has happened is that small enterprises and big enterprises have both grown in scale so what we now call a small enterprise may be large by some earlier standard. However, the thesis that Schumpeter developed is certainly sophisticated and subtle and deserves serious attention.

THERE IS ANOTHER DIRECTION, it seems to me, in which there is a different kind of a tendency for capitalism to undermine itself by its own success. The tendency I have in mind can probably best be brought out by the experience of Great Britain—Great Britain tends to provide the best laboratory for many of these forces. It has to do with the attitude of the public at large toward law and toward law obedience. Britain has a wide and deserved reputation for the extraordinary obedience of its people to the law. It has not always been so. At the turn of the nineteenth century, and earlier, the British had a very different reputation as a nation of people who would obey no law, or almost no law, a nation of smugglers, a nation in which corruption and inefficiency was rife, and in which one could not get very much done through governmental channels.

Indeed, one of the factors that led Bentham and the Utilitarians toward laisser-faire, and this is a view that is also expressed by Dicey, was the self-evident truth that if you wanted to get evils corrected, you could not expect to do so through the government of the time. The government was corrupt and inefficient. It was clearly oppressive. It was something that had to be gotten out of the way as a first step to reform. The fundamental philosophy of the Utilitarians, or any philosophy that puts its emphasis on some kind of a sum of utilities, however loose may be the expression, does not lead to laisser-faire in principle. It leads to whatever kind of organization of economic activity is thought to produce results which are regarded as good in the sense of adding to the sum total of utilities. I think the major reason why the Utilitarians tended to be in favor of laisser-faire was the obvious fact that government was incompetent to perform any of the tasks they wanted to see performed.

Whatever the reason for its appeal, the adoption of laisser-faire had some important consequences. Once laisser-faire was adopted, the economic incentive for corruption was largely removed. After all, if governmental officials had no favors to grant, there was no need to bribe them. And if there was nothing to be gained from government, it could hardly be a source of corruption. Moreover, the laws that were left were for the most part, and again I am oversimplifying and exaggerating, laws that were widely accepted as proper and desirable; laws against theft, robbery, murder, etc. This is in sharp contrast to a situation in which the legislative structure designates as crimes what people individually do not regard as crimes or makes it illegal for people to do what seems to them the sensible thing. The latter situation tends to reduce respect for the law. One of the unintended and indirect effects of laisser-faire was thus to establish a climate in Britain of a much greater degree of obedience and respect for the law than had existed earlier. Probably there were other forces at work in this development but I believe that the establishment of laisser-faire laid the groundwork for a reform in the civil service in the latter part of the century—the establishment of a civil service chosen on the basis of examinations and merit and of professional competence. You could get that kind of development because the incentives to seek such places for purposes of exerting “improper” influence were greatly reduced when government had few favors to confer.

In these ways, the development of laisser-faire laid the groundwork for a widespread respect for the law, on the one hand, and a relatively incorrupt, honest, and efficient civil service on the other, both of which are essential preconditions for the operation of a collectivist society. In order for a collectivist society to operate, the people must obey the laws and there must be a civil service that can and will carry out the laws. The success of capitalism established these preconditions for a movement in the direction of much greater state intervention.

The process I have described obviously runs both ways. A movement in the direction of a collectivist society involves increased governmental intervention into the daily lives of people and the conversion into crimes of actions that are regarded by the ordinary person as entirely proper. These tend in turn to undermine respect for the law and to give incentives to corrupt state officials. There can, I think, be little doubt that this process has begun in Britain and has gone a substantial distance. Although respect for the law may still be greater than it is here, most observers would agree that respect for the law in Britain has gone down decidedly in the course of the last twenty or thirty years, certainly since the war, as a result of the kind of laws people have been asked to obey. On the occasions I have been in England, I have had access to two sources of information that generally yield quite different answers. One is people associated with academic institutions, all of whom are quite shocked at the idea that any British citizen might evade the law—except perhaps for transactions involving exchanging pounds for dollars when exchange control was in effect. It also happens that I had contact with people engaged in small businesses. They tell a rather different story, and one that I suspect comes closer to being valid, about the extent to which regulations were honored in the breach, and taxes and customs regulations evaded—the one thing that is uniform among people or almost uniform is that nobody or almost nobody has any moral repugnance to smuggling, and certainly not when he is smuggling something into some country other than his own.

The erosion of the capital stock of willingness to obey the law reduces the capacity of a society to run a centralized state, to move away from freedom. This effect on law obedience is thus one that is reversible and runs in both directions. It is another major factor that needs to be taken into account in judging the likely stability of a free system in the long run.

I HAVE BEEN EMPHASIZING forces and approaches that are mostly pessimistic in terms of our values in the sense that most of them are reasons why a free society is likely to be unstable and to change into a collectivist system. I should like therefore to turn to some of the tendencies that may operate in the other direction.

What are the sources of strength for a free society that may help to maintain it? One of the major sources of strength is the tendency for extension of economic intervention in a wide range of areas to interfere directly and clearly with political liberty and thus to make people aware of the conflict between the two. This has been the course of events in Great Britain after the war and in many other countries. I need not repeat or dwell on this point.

A second source of strength is one that has already been suggested by my comments on law obedience. In many ways, perhaps the major hope for a free society is precisely that feature in a free society which makes it so efficient and productive in its economic activity; namely, the ingenuity of millions of people, each of whom is trying to further his own interest, in part by finding ways to get around state regulation. If I may refer to my own casual observation of Britain and France a few years after the war, the impression that I formed on the the basis of very little evidence but that seemed to me to be supported by further examination was that Britain at the time was being economically strangled by the law obedience of her citizens while France was being saved by the existence of the black market. The price system is a most effective and efficient system for organizing resources. So long as people try to make it operate, it can surmount a lot of problems. There is the famous story about the man who wrote a letter to Adam Smith, saying that some policy or other was going to be the ruin of England. And Adam Smith, as I understand the story, wrote back and said, “Young man, there is a lot of ruin in a nation.”

This seems to me an important point. Once government embarks on intervention into and regulation of private activities, this establishes an incentive for large numbers of individuals to use their ingenuity to find ways to get around the government regulations. One result is that there appears to be a lot more regulation than there really is. Another is that the time and energy of government officials is increasingly taken up with the need to plug the holes in the regulations that the citizens are finding, creating, and exploiting. From this point of view, Parkinson’s law about the growth of bureaucracy without a corresponding growth of output may be a favorable feature for the maintenance of a free society. An efficient governmental organization and not an inefficient one is almost surely the greater threat to a free society. One of the virtues of a free society is precisely that the market tends to be a more efficient organizing principle than centralized direction. Centralized direction in this way is always having to fight something of a losing battle.

Very closely related to this point and perhaps only another aspect of it is the difference between the “visibility” of monopolistic action whether governmental or private and of actions through the market. When people are acting through the market, millions of people are engaging in activities in a variety of ways that are highly impersonal, not very well recognized, and almost none of which attracts attention. On the other hand, governmental actions, and this is equally true of actions by private monopolies, whether of labor or industry, tend to be conducted by persons who get into the headlines, to attract notice. I have often conducted the experiment of asking people to list the major industries in the United States. In many ways, the question is a foolish one because there is no clear definition of industry. Yet people have some concept of industry and the interesting thing is that the result is always very similar. People always list those industries in which there is a high degree of concentration. They list the automobile industry, never the garment industry, although the garment industry is far larger by any economic measure than the automobile industry. I have never had anybody list the industry of providing domestic service although it employs many more people than the steel industry. Estimates of importance are always biased in the direction of those industries that are monopolized or concentrated and so are in the hands of few firms. Everybody knows the names of the leading producers of automobiles. Few could list the leading producers of men’s and women’s clothing, or of furniture, although these are both very large industries. So competition, working through the market, precisely because it is impersonal, anonymous, and works its way in devious channels, tends to be underestimated in importance, and the kinds of personal activities that are associated with government, with monopoly, with trade unions, tend to be exaggerated in importance.

Because this kind of direct personal activity by large organizations, whether it be governmental or private, is visible, it tends to call attention to itself out of all proportion to its economic importance. The result is that the community tends to be awakened to the dangers arising from such activities and such concentration of power before they become so important that it is too late to do anything about them. This phenomenon is very clear for trade unions. Everybody has been reading in the newspapers about the negotiations in steel and knows that there is a labor problem in the steel industry. The negotiations usually terminate in some kind of wage increase that is regarded as attributable to the union’s activities. In the post war period, domestic servants have gotten larger wage increases without anyone engaging in large scale negotiations, without anyone’s knowing that negotiations were going on and without a single newspaper headline except perhaps to record complaints about the problem of finding domestic servants. I think that trade unions have much monopoly power. But I think the importance of trade unions is widely exaggerated, that they are nothing like so important in the allocation of labor or the determination of wage rates as they are supposed to be. They are not unimportant—perhaps 10 or 15% of the working force have wages now some 10 or 15% higher than they otherwise would be because of trade unions, and the remaining 85% of the working class have wages something like 4% lower than they would otherwise be. This is appreciable and important, but it does not give unions the kind of power over the economy that would make it impossible to check their further rise.

The three major sources of strength I have suggested so far are the corroding effect of the extension of state activities and state intervention on attitudes toward the enforcement of the law and on the character of the civil service; the ingenuity of individuals in avoiding regulation; and the visibility of government action and of monopoly. Implicit in these is a fourth, namely the general inefficiency in the operation of government.

These comments have been rather discursive. I have been attempting simply to list some of the forces at work tending to destroy a free society once established, and tending to resist its destruction. I have left out of consideration the force that in some ways is our most important concern; namely, the force of ideas, of people’s attitudes about values and about the kind of social organization that they want. I have omitted this force because I have nothing to say about it that is not self-evident.

No very clear conclusion can be drawn from this examination of the forces adverse and favorable to a free society. The historical record suggests pessimism, but the analysis gives no strong basis for either great optimism or confirmed pessimism about the stablity of a free society, if it is given an opportunity to exist. One of the most important tasks for liberal scholars to undertake is to examine this issue more fully in the light of historical evidence in order that we may have a much better idea of what factors tend to promote and what factors to destroy a free society.

[* ] Milton Friedman, Professor of Economics at the University of Chicago, is an Editorial Advisor to New Individualist Review. His most recent book is Price Theory.

Source: New Individualist Review, editor-in-chief Ralph Raico, introduction by Milton Friedman (Indianapolis: Liberty Fund, 1981). Chapter: MILTON FRIEDMAN, Is a Free Society Stable?

Recalling the ‘Doctor’s Plot’ Purim Miracle

Stalin and the Purim Miracle

 

Stalin had plans to murder millions of Russian Jews. Like Haman, the tables suddenly turned.


Jewish holidays are not merely a commemoration of an event in time. The time of year in which the miracle occurred was an opportune time for the conception of that miracle. As we make our way toward the Purim holiday, we are entering a time zone in which all the Hamans of the world can fail and Jewish redemption is born. The death and downfall of Stalin is an example of a miraculous, yet untold, modern-day Purim story.

Joseph Stalin, tyrant of communist Russia dubbed the invincible “man of steel,” who murdered approximately 20,000,000 of his own people, was particularly hateful toward the Jews. After World War Two, his anti-Semitic campaign took a more aggressive, public stance. In 1947, he targeted thousands of Jewish scientists, politicians, and intellectuals who were dismissed from their positions, humiliated, arrested, and tortured. Stalin’s infamous Doctor’s Plot, in which six Jewish doctors were arrested and tortured into making a confession, began with the Stalin-controlled media spreading rumors that Jewish doctors were poisoning Russian children by injecting them with diphtheria and killing infants in hospital wards. (Daily Mail, National Journal, 2003)

After spreading his toxic rumors about Jews to the public, Stalin carried on with his plans to eliminate Russia’s two to four million Jews, by deporting them to the freezing, uninhabitable regions of Russia and leaving them to die of starvation, hypothermia, and disease. An article from the National Journal in 2003 reported that newly discovered documents proved that in February of 1953, Stalin commissioned the construction of four camps in Kazakhstan, Siberia and in the Arctic North. The conjecture about Stalin’s genocidal plans was confirmed by P.K. Ponomarenko, Soviet Ambassador in Poland, in an article in the French Newspaper, ‘Paris-Soir’.

“A week before the Purim of 1953… Jewish faces were far from merry,” recounted Mrs. Batyah Barg, author of the autobiography Voices in the Silence. “In train stations all over Russia, train cars were being requisitioned to carry huge caravans of Jews into exile and slow death. Reliable sources confirmed that the expulsion would begin on the sixth of March, just a few days after Purim” (pg. 216).

God will yet help…. Stalin is a mere mortal… no one can know what will be with him in a half hour.

Rabbi Yitzchak Zilber, another Jewish hero and author of the autobiography, To Remain a Jew, recounts this climatic time during which he was imprisoned in the frosty region of Siberia. After Rabbi Zilber read the Book of Esther recounting the miracle of Purim to a group of Jewish prisoners, one prisoner responded, “Who needs your tales about what happened 2,500 years ago? Tell me, where is your God today? It’s not enough that Hitler finished six million – here they are about to be done with another three. Do you not see the trains and the barracks that have already been built (for this purpose)?” To which the fearless Rabbi Zilber replied, “True, our situation is difficult, but don’t be so quick to eulogize us. Haman also sent orders to 127 provinces. God will yet help…. Stalin is a mere mortal… no one can know what will be with him in a half hour.” (pg. 236- 237)

That Purim night, a few days before the Jewish doctors were due to go to trial, and just thirty minutes after Rabbi Zilber’s foretelling of Stalin’s vulnerable fate, Stalin was said to have “collapsed in a fit of rage” during a meeting in which his supporters expressed opposition to his evil plan, according to the Jewish Telegraphic Agency. That Purim, thousands of Jewish prisoners were freed. Joseph Stalin died on March 5, just a few days later, to the great relief of Russian Jewry. “To this day, I am choked with emotion every time I think back to that Purim of miracles,” recounts Mrs. Batyah Barg.

May we continue to re-experience the miracles of our holidays each and every year.

From Aish.com, here.

Children Should Not Consume Alcohol – Even on Purim!

PURIM SAFETY GUIDELINES FROM JEWISH COMMUNITY WATCH

Purim is a really fun time for kids and adults alike, and it means lots of visiting family and friends! It’s important to keep in mind that 95% of abuse occurs at the hands of someone well known to the child, which makes it so important to stay educated and proactive while avoiding unnecessary panic or anxiety (which is detrimental to kids). Whether you’re away visiting others or having lots of guests, safety rules are a must!

  • Children need to know that if anyone offers them alcohol, they must tell you immediately. It is both illegal and dangerous for minors to consume alcohol. It is also important to remember that children are very small people, and the effects of even a small amount of alcohol can be magnified significantly. A child under the influence of alcohol, in an unnaturally uninhibited state, with decreased ability to resist, and with impaired memory faculties, is a high risk of being abused and hurt.
  • Sometimes, as excited as we are about seeing friends and relatives, it’s easy to forget that our usual personal boundaries still apply. Remind your friends and relatives that if your child wants to skip the hugs and kisses this time, that should be their choice. Even the most loving and well-meaning family member can cause a child confusion about owning their body, by forcing them to give hugs and kisses when they don’t want to.
  • While treats and sweets are an important part of Purim for kids, your children should be reminded that accepting treats should only be done with your permission.
  • As always, pay attention to adults or older teens who are paying extra special attention to your kids. There are plenty of great, healthy adults who enjoy spending lots of time with children, but in general, adults and children should want to be spending time with people their own age. Trust your gut feelings, and your children’s instincts – if they don’t want to spend time with a certain relative or friend, don’t force them. Give them a chance to discuss it with you in a relaxed, non-pressured environment.
  • As always, your child should be reminded that secrets should never be kept from parents. If anyone asks your child to come with them somewhere, without telling you, the answer should be NO! (even if it’s someone he/she knows well)

The staff and volunteers of Jewish Community Watch wish all of you and your children a happy and safe Purim!

Check out these important articles on our site for more information on how to protect your children:

5 TIPS TO KEEP YOUR CHILDREN SAFE THIS HOLIDAY SEASON!

LOOK FOR AND READ BODY LANGUAGE

IN THE HOME